#Kenneth Becker
Explore tagged Tumblr posts
wutbju · 9 months ago
Photo
Tumblr media
BJU Missionary Unit has 38 Workers in Four Continents
Not only is Bob Jones University called the "World's Most Unusual University," but its call-letters also could stand for "Worldwide Ministry Unto Unevangelized." The embodiment of this aspect of the university's international influence is found in Gospel Fellowship Missions, the foreign mission society whose office and headquarters are on the campus.
GFM is one of the more recent ministries begun by the university. This independent faith mission completed its fifth year of organized missionary activity. It has grown yearly and now has 38 workers in 11 fields scattered around the world in four continents.
Including two fields established this summer in Korea and Mexico, GFM missionaries are to be found in the Far East -- Japan and Korea; South America -- Chile and Brazil; North America -- Barbados, Puerto Rico, Mexico, and Hawaii; Northern Europe -- Sweden and West Germany; and the Middle East --  Lebanon.
Administratively, the mission operates separately from the university and is a part of the Gospel Fellowship Association, chartered as a nonprofit organization in 1940. Through the years GFA has sponsored many kinds of evangelistic ministries through literature, radio, newspaper evangelism, films and evangelistic crusades.
A faith mission board like Gospel Fellowship Missions operates differently from a nominational mission society. The faith mission does not manipulate or salary its workers from a central board and treasury. However, it provides a source of counsel and finances for the missionary. The co-ordination of the total field program as well as the direction of personal ministries can be administered only through the board.
The missionary on the field needs a representative with the United States government as well as with the government of the country in which he is laboring. The board maintains the tie of fellowship between the missionaries on the field and the supporting churches in the homeland.
Tumblr media
BECKER IS HEAD
The mission office, located in the Administration Building at BJU, is staffed by two full-time employees, Rev. Kenneth D. Becker, the executive secretary, and Mrs. Corban Tabler, office secretary. Board policy and decision is executed by a seven-member executive committee, consisting of executives and deans of the university. This is backed up by a board of trustees composed of 35 Christians around the country, among whom are pastors, evangelists, educators and laymen.
The nerve center of the worldwide work is in the home office. Donations from over 1,200 supporting churches and friends in 47 states and several foreign countries are received by the home office for the missionaries and their ministries. Each donation is acknowledged with a personal letter describing the current news of the missionary supported. At the end of the month, all missionary accounts are totaled and checks mailed around the world.
In order to maintain the personal touch and keep up with the load of correspondence, data processing equipment and a high-speed typewriter are leased. Because of this personal touch, donors are not only sup. porters, but also enthusiasts of the mission and missionaries, as they have frequently noted in correspondence. The mission office staff keeps a steady stream of information flowing to those who support the work through gifts and prayers.
The oldest GFM field is in Japan. Six missionaries there are working in tent evangelism, founding churches, training national pastors, Bible correspondence courses, literature and street evangelism, and children's and youth work.
Gospel Fellowship Mission's most recent field is in Mexico. It was founded by a Mexican national, Jose Lara, in his home area in Central Mexico. His father was one of the earliest converts to Christianity in the whole region, and Mr. Lara had the distinction of being reared in an evangelical home.
There are six national evangelists and as many as 75 little churches -- some having only one or two families -- in the mountains who look to Mr. Lara and his ministry. He intends to establish a Christian trade school, along with the evangelistic effort in the villages, to train the Mexican Christians in skills so that they can support their families and the church.
The precarious international situation was impressed upon the mission by the recent Middle East war. Lebanon was one of the mission's early fields, and the missionary family was on furlough when hostilities broke out. There may be a delay before the ministry will be re-established, and even then it may take a long time to overcome anti-American hostilities and the damage which has befallen many friends and converts of the missionary.
0 notes
downthetubes · 1 year ago
Text
Stewart Kenneth Moore's "The Tragedie of Macbeth", "Project MK-Ultra" collections on the way from Clover Press
US publisher Clover Press will release a collection of 2000AD creator Stewart Kenneth Moore's graphic novel version of Macbeth early next month
US publisher Clover Press will release a collection of 2000AD creator Stewart Kenneth Moore‘s graphic novel version of Macbeth early next month, which they began serialising last year. They’re also publishing Project MK-Ultra: The Complete Edition in October. Stewart will be signing copies of the new collection at Gosh, London this Saturday (1.00 – 2.00pm, 30th September) – full details…
Tumblr media
View On WordPress
3 notes · View notes
ivovynckier · 1 year ago
Text
youtube
The end of a career: the deputy mayor (John Cusack) forces the mayor (Al Pacino) to resign.
The movie was written by Kenneth Lipper, a childhood friend of Al Pacino and a deputy mayor of New York under Ed Koch.
2 notes · View notes
drzito · 10 months ago
Text
Las 242 peliculas que he visto en 2023 (parte 1)
Tarzan y su compañera (Cedric Gibbons, 1934).
2. El fantasma y la Sra Muir (Joseph L Mankiewicz, 1947)
3. Odio entre hermanos (Joseph L Mankiewicz, 1949)
4. Testigo accidental (Richard Fleischer, 1952)
5. El rastro de la pantera (William A Wellman, 1954)
6. El tigre dormido (Joseph Losey, 1954)
7. El quinteto de la muerte (Alexander McKendrick, 1955)
8. 40 pistolas (Samuel Fuller, 1957)
9. La maldición de Frankenstein (Terence Fisher, 1957)
10. Ocho horas de terror (Seijun Suzuki, 1957)
11. The Trollenberg terror (Quentin Lawrence, 1958)
12. La Venganza (Juan Antonio Bardem, 1958)
13. Un golpe de gracia (Jack Arnold, 1959)
14. A todo riesgo (Claude Sautet, 1960)
15. La evasion (Jacques Becker, 1960)
16. El sabor del miedo (Seth Holt, 1961)
17. Detective bureau 2 3. Go to hell bastards! (Seijun Suzuki, 1963)
18. The white tiger tattoo (Seijun Suzuki, 1965)
19. A traves del huracan (Monte Hellman, 1966)
20. El Tiroteo (Monte Hellman, 1966)
21. La soltera retozona (Silvio Narizzano, 1966)
22. Dimension 5 (Franklin Adreon, 1966)
23. Los Productores (Mel Brooks, 1967)
24. Un hombre (Martin Ritt, 1967)
25. Sebastian (David Greene, 1968)
26. El Bastardo (Duccio Tessari, 1968)
27. El lagarto negro (Kinji Fukasaku, 1968)
28. La louve solitaire (Edouard Logereau, 1968)
29. Aquel dia frio en el parque (Robert Altman, 1969)
30. Corazones en fuga (Michael Powell, 1969)
31. La bestia ciega (Yasuzo Masumura, 1969).
32. El bosque del lobo (Pedro Olea, 1970)
33. El grito del fantasma (Gordon Hessler, 1970)
34. Drácula y las mellizas (John Hough, 1971).
35. ¡Que viene Valdez! (Edwin Sherin, 1971)
36. Sangre en la tumba de la momia (Seth Holt, 1971)
37. El Otro (Robert Mulligan, 1972)
38. Hermanas (Brian de Palma, 1972)
39. Imagenes (Robert Altman, 1972)
40. Morgiana (Juraj Herz, 1972)
41. El ataque de los muertos sin ojos (Amando de Ossorio, 1973)
42. El programa final (Robert Fuest, 1973)
43. Flor de santidad (Adolfo Marsillach, 1973)
44. Lemora, un cuento sobrenatural (Richard Blackburn, 1973)
45. Messiah of Evil (Willard Huyck y Gloria Katz, 1973)
46. Una vela para el diablo (Eugenio Martin, 1973).
47. Daguerrotipos (Agnes Varda, 1975)
48. La noche de las gaviotas (Armando de Ossorio, 1975)
49. Picnic en Hanging Rock (Peter Weir, 1975)
50. El otro Sr Klein (Joseph Losey, 1976)
51. Terror al anochecer (Charles B Pierce, 1976)
52. El desafio del bufalo blanco (J Lee Thompson, 1977)
53. Largo fin de semana (Colin Eggleston, 1978)
54. El grito (Jerzy Skolimowski, 1978)
55. Los ojos del bosque (John Hough, 1980)
56. Alison’s birthday (Ian Coughlan, 1981)
57. Muertos y enterrados (Gary Sherman, 1981)
58. Wilczyca (Marek Piestrak, 1983)
59. En compañia de lobos (Neil Jordan, 1984).
60. Sangre Facil (Joel Coen, 1984)
61. Sole survivor: Unico superviviente (Thom Eberhardt, 1984)
62. Tasio (Montxo Armendariz, 1984)
63. El tren del infierno (Andréi Konchalovski, 1985)
64. El corazon del angel (Alan Parker, 1987)
65. Jovenes Ocultos (Joel Schumacher, 1987)
66. La chaqueta metalica (Stanley Kubrick, 1987)
67. El fluir de las lagrimas (Won Kar Wai, 1988)
68. Ensalada de gemelas (Jim Abrahams, 1988)
69. Kadaicha, la piedra de la muerte (James Bogle, 1988)
70. Pacto de Sangre (Stan Winston, 1988)
71. Avalon (Barry Levinson, 1990).
72. Misery (Rob Reiner, 1990)
73. La Teranyina (Antoni Verdaguer, 1990)
74. La Tutora (William Friedkin, 1990)
75. Morir Todavia (Kenneth Branagh, 1990)
76. La jungla de cristal 2 (Renny Harlin, 1990)
77. Solo en casa (Chris Columbus, 1990)
78. Alien 3 (David Fincher, 1992)
79. Mi novia es un zombi (Michele Soavi, 1994)
80. Nadja (Michael Almereyda, 1994)
81. Esto (no) es un secuestro (Ted Demme, 1994)
82. Dos Policias Rebeldes (Michael Bay, 1995)
83. El demonio vestido de azul (Carl Franklin, 1995)
84. Heat (Michael Mann, 1995)
85. Jovenes y brujas (Andrew Fleming, 1996)
86. Agarrame esos fantasmas (Peter Jackson, 1996)
87. Herbert's Hippopotamus: Marcuse and Revolution in Paradise (Paul Alexander Juutilainen, 1996).
88. La Roca (Michael Bay, 1996)
89. Tierra (Julio Medem, 1996)
90. 99.9. La frecuencia del terror (Agusti Villaronga, 1997)
91. Fallen (Gregory Hoblit, 1998)
92. Un plan sencillo (Sam Raimi, 1998)
93. El halcon ingles (Steven Soderbergh, 1999).
94. Ilusiones de un mentiroso (Peter Kassovitz. 1999)
95. Flores de otro mundo (Iciar Bollain, 1999)
96. Ravenous (Antonia Bird, 1999)
97. Wisconsin Death Trip (James Marsh, 1999)
98. Dagon: La secta del mar (Stuart Gordon, 2001)
99. Escalofrio (Bill Paxton, 2001)
100. Dracula: Pages from a Virgin's Diary (Guy Maddin, 2002)
101. 2 hermanas (Jee-Woon Kim, 2003)
102. Dos policias rebeldes II (Michael Bay, 2003)
103. Los Angeles Play Itself (Thom Andersen, 2003)
104. El reportero: La leyenda de Ron Burgundy (Adam McKay, 2004)
105. El Septimo Dia (Carlos Saura, 2004)
106. La vida que te espera (Manuel Gutierrez Aragon, 2004)
107. Los Edukadores (Hans Weingartner, 2004)
108. Misteriosa obsesion (Joseph Ruben, 2004)
109. Yo, Robot (Alex Proyas, 2004)
110. Hostel (Eli Roth, 2005)
111. Wolf Creek (Greg McLean, 2005)
112. Bajo cero (Frank Marshall, 2006)
113. El Inadaptado (Jens Lien, 2006)
114. Sheitan (Kim Chapiron, 2006)
115. The last winter (Larry Fessenden, 2006)
116. 30 dias de oscuridad (David Slade, 2007)
117. Borderland. Al otro lado de la frontera (Zev Berman, 2007)
118. Diarios de la calle (Richard LaGravenese, 2007)
119. Frontera(s) (Xavier Gens, 2007)
120. Hostel 2 (Eli Roth, 2007)
121. Water Lilies (Celine Sciamma, 2007)
2 notes · View notes
power-chords · 1 year ago
Text
Also, if we're being real, Kenneth Burke is pre-Becker Becker! And Becker got a Pulitzer for The Denial of Death!
4 notes · View notes
sodascherrycola · 2 years ago
Text
Instagram Intros (Keith Richard’s Kids)
Tumblr media
Adrian James Richards (@adrianrichards)
DOB: August 17th 1969 Age: 54 years old Hometown: Sussex, England Nicknames: Adri S/O: Penelope Maple Kids: Noah, Kenneth, Ethan, and Jane Friend(s): Zoe Jagger and Jason Browning Aesthetic: A hard worker, and just SUCH a DAD!!! He is so protective over his children. He was never close with his dad and def has major daddy issues that are undignosed. He wants to be the dad he never had around. He adores his kids more than anything else. Loves his mom and appreciates her more now that he's older.
Tumblr media
Jamie Robert Richards (@jamierichards)
DOB: September 1st 1972 Age: 51 years old Hometown: Sussex, England Nicknames: James S/O: Kelly Montgomery Kids: Jenna, Victoria, and Eliza Friend(s): Ava Jagger Aesthetic: When he was 16 and his parents got divorced he acted out like crazy. He was partying and doing drugs and just running wild. Became a total pain to BOTH of his parents and they knew something was up. He was surprisinly fond of his father and they got along quite well, so when he divorced his mom shit went down. He is just a bit too much like Keith in a way.
Tumblr media
Amelia Zoe Richards (@mia_richards)
DOB: July 3rd 1976 Age: 47 years old Hometown: Sussex, England Nicknames: Mia, Mila S/O: Nicholas Urie Kids: Jaiden, Olivia, and Taylor Friend(s): Alice Lindsey and Jennifer Weiss Aesthetic: The kindest out of all her siblings. Loves being a girly girl and dressing up for brunch. The spitting image of her mother and Keith adores it. She looks and acts just like her mom, from her eyes straight down to the mannerisms she uses. Head to toe Lucy.
Tumblr media
Evie Lynn Richards (@evielynn)
DOB: November 18th 1978 Age: 45 years old Hometown: Sussex, England Nicknames: Eve S/O: Sierra Lynch Kids: Noel and Everly Friend(s): Henry Burke Aesthetic: The shy kid. She never was really one for the spotlight but never acted out from it. She knew she had a good reputation from a young age and was a people pleaser. One wrong move and she would be done for and everyone would hate her. She was always nice with the paparazzi and in interviews. She was the press' princess since she was born.
Tumblr media
Sophie Anne Richards (@soph.richie)
DOB: December 2nd 1985 Age: 38 years old Hometown: Sussex, England Nicknames: Soph S/O: Joshua Green Kids: Hannah Friend(s): Sloane Becker and Gregory Phillips Aesthetic: A literal model. She is stunning and she knows it. She uses it to her advantage, and her dad taught her that. He loved her the most secretly but he would never tell. She became the youngest model to be on the cover of Vouge when she was just 16 years old. When she dated Damon Albarn from 2006-2008 it caused quite the stir because of their age gap. People thought it was another case of her parents. It was, and they broke up after about 2 years.
Tumblr media
Alexander Cole Richards (@alexcrich)
DOB: October 13th 1986 Age: 37 years old Hometown: Sussex, England Nicknames: Al, Alex, Lexi, and Xander S/O: Natalie Bell Kids: Juliana, Damien, and Jaxon Friend(s): Zackary Best Aesthetic: Alexander was the glue holding this family on by the thread. A lot of fighting goes on in this family and he has always hated it. He's always the one to bring people back together to make things right, the therepist friend if you will. He has a lot of issues he refuses to talk about just to avoid conflict.
Tumblr media
Charlotte Grace Richards (@helllooo_charliii)
DOB: December 18th 2001 Age: 22 years old Hometown: Sussex, England Nickames: Charlie and Lottie S/O: Hallie Carpenter Kids: None Friend(s): Loralai Mendoza Aesthetic: The youngest, and a complete accident on her parents part. She was not planned but loved nevertheless. Her older siblings love her because she's so little to them. Her parents never had to pay for a babysitter because they had her brothers and sisters. She was a very adventurous kid and loved the outdoors. Had a lot of pet snails too.
4 notes · View notes
keynewssuriname · 6 months ago
Text
Menzo geeft WK-kwalificatie van voorselectie prijs
Tumblr media
Natio-bondscoach Stanley Menzo heeft in aanloop naar de WK-kwalificatiewedstrijden volgende maand de de voorselectie prijsgegeven. Opvallende namen zijn ongetwijfeld die van Etienne Vaessen (RKC Waalwijk) en Gyrano Kerk (Royal Antwerp). Het duo werd al geruime tijd in verband gebracht met de mannen voetbalselectie van Suriname, maar enkele zaken moesten nog worden afgerond. Nu is dat een feit en kunnen ze officieel voor Natio uitkomen. Behalve Vaessen en Kerk bestond de kans dat de bondstrainer ook Immanuel Pherai (Hamburger SV), Danilho Doekhi (Union Berlin), Deyovaisio Zeefuik (Hertha BSC), Richonell Margaret (RKC Waalwijk), Jayden Turfkruier (Telstar) en Denzel Jubitana (Atromitos) zou kunnen verwelkomen. Dit zestal is echter niet geselecteerd. Blijkbaar zijn hun zaken nog niet in orde. Ook Ché Nunnely, die vóór de vriendschappelijke interland tegen Martinique op 24 maart aan het publiek was gepresenteerd, is opvallend genoeg afwezig. Radinio Balker, die wel deel uitmaakte van de selectie tegen Martinique, is ook niet in de voorselectie opgenomen. Balker kon vanwege een blessure zijn Natio debuut tegen Martinique niet maken. De 4 lokale spelers in de voorselectie zijn allen Robinhooders. Het gaat om doelman Jonathan Fonkel, centrumverdediger Allierio Belfor, middenvelder Renske Adipi en vleugelaanvaller tevens aanvoerder Jamilhio Rigters. Kelvin Leerdam, Jeredy Hilterman, Navajo Bakboord, Gleofilo Vlijter en Leandro Kappel zijn weer van de partij. Het nationaal team komt, zoals Menzo eerder tegenover Keynews zei, volgens planning al op 29 mei bijeen. Op papier staan de WK-kwalificatiewedstrijden tegen Saint Vincent and The Grenadines (5 juni Franklin Essedstadion) en Anguilla (8 juni Ronald Webster Park). Volledig overzicht voorselectie: Doelverdedigers: Warner Hahn (Kyoto Sanga), Joey Roggeveen (FC Tulsa), Ishan Kort (BE 1 Academia), Jonathan Fonkel (Robinhood) en Etienne Vaessen (RKC Waalwijk). Verdedigers: Stefano Denswil (Trabzonspor), Navajo Bakboord (Heracles Almelo), Anfernee Dijksteel (Middlesbrough), Djevencio van der Kust (Sparta Rotterdam), Damil Dankerlui (Panserraikos), Myenty Abena (Ferencvárosi), Shaquille Pinas (Hammarby), Ridgeciano Haps (Genoa) en Allierio Belfor (Robinhood). Middenvelders: Dion Malone (Karmiotissa), Kelvin Leerdam (Heracles Almelo), Dhoraso Klas (ADO Den Haag), Kenneth Paal (Queens Park Rangers), Justin Lonwijk (Fortuna Sittard) en Renske Adipi (Robinhood). Aanvallers: Jeredy Hilterman (WILLEM II), Florian Jozefzoon (Bandirmaspor), Sheraldo Becker (Real Sociedad), Yanic Wildschut (Exeter City), Luciano Slagveer (Puskas Akademia), Leandro Kappel (Pendikspor), Virgil Misidjan (Al Tai), Jamilhio Rigters (Robinhood), Tyrone Conraad (Meizhou Hakka), Jaden Montnor (Aris Limassol), Gyrano Kerk (Royal Antwerp) en Gleofilo Vlijter (Vaasan Pallosuer). Read the full article
0 notes
happymeishappylife · 11 months ago
Text
Comics/Graphic Novels I Read in 2023 (Part 2)
11. March Book 3 by John Lewis, Andrew Aydin, and Nate Powell
Tumblr media
We finally got the coverage of Bloody Sunday and the heartbreaking horrible acts committed before, around, and after this day. But this story also led up to the passing of the Civil Rights Act and the fight it was to get that approved. While all our problems may not be solved, its hard not be proud of the progress that has been made. We must not let it go backwards and we all must fight. It was great to read this too before I went to Atlanta and to the Civil Rights Museum where its emphasized that we must all fight if we want real change. And that means willing to get hurt.
12. They Called Us Enemy by George Takei, Justin Eisinger, Steven Scott, and Harmony Becker
Tumblr media
A powerful first hand account of one of the most atrocious acts in United States History. When we, like Germany, decided a whole group of people were the enemy even though they were fully immigrated and living American lives when Japan bombed Pearl Harbor. Seeing Takei describe the things he saw through his childhood and youthful eyes while also seeing the things his parents do as an adult made it hard because so much of it felt like what happened in Germany and Polland, but without the gas chambers. That doesn’t make it okay, that we didn’t kill these people. In fact its horrific the way we treated them and its important story to tell. I also appreciate that Takei has been so vocal about it and has tried to tell it through so many mediums. I went and saw Allegiance a couple weeks after it first opened and was sad it wasn’t a smash hit because it was a great musical and powerful story. But the main takeaway is we can’t forget our history and we can’t erase it. We need to own it and make it better for those who have suffered and make sure it never happens again.
13. Iyanu: Child of Wonder Volume 1 by Roye Okupe with Godwin Akpan
Tumblr media
I loved this introduction book into a world so steeped in African folklore and with a mystery and fantasy element to add suspense and intrigue. In this novel we meet Inayu. A forest girl who we learn survived after her parents died and became a student of a woman who is part of the Olori, the first people to have magic and mystical powers. In this world, the magic has all but disappeared and the animals have been poisoned to be more dangerous and alert. But Iyanu, who sneaks into the village from time to time, has the power of the wonder which means she is a child of prophecy. One that must be hunted by the now leader of the village for it means she is a threat. Can’t wait to see where we go in this journey with Iyanu into the histories of Yorubuland.
14. Red Hood and the Outlaws Volume 1: Redemption by Scott Lobdell and Kenneth Rocafort
Tumblr media
The more I keep interacting with Batman media, the more intriguing I find Jason Todd’s story which is why I picked this up. I want to learn more about this former Robin and how he was brought back from the dead, how he deals with crime, but also how is a former hero underneath. And while I’m not up to his full history of lore, I do like that the story focuses on him avenging the order who saved his soul after he came out of the Lazarus pit. And while this isn’t Bizarro and Artemis (like the Webtoon I’m reading) I do like this dynamic of Roy Harper and Starfire, mainly because I have always like Roy and its nice to know more of his story. The blatant oversexualized styling of Starfire is unnecessary though and something that will be hard to read through. I didn’t realize the cover art was a way to hide that but thankfully the rest of the story is interesting enough to continue.
15. Saga Volume 4 by Brian K. Vaughan and Fiona Staples
Tumblr media
Got to admit, this one became a little bit more tough to get through, but it felt realistic. It’s been a couple years since we have seen everyone and we learn Alana has become a TV actor who gets way too hooked on recreational drugs to do her job probably, Marko is trying to be a good Dad, but has to constantly hide his face so they aren’t recognized, and Prince Robot the IV has been hiding out on a space brothel where he learns of the murder of his wife and the kidnapping of his newborn son. Of course things unravel and people split up, but I wasn’t expecting Marko and Prince Robot the IV to team up. I doubt this will go well in the long run.
16. Saga Volume 5 by Brian K. Vaughan and Fiona Staples
Tumblr media
As we learn from Hazel in this novel, it may be that her parents never get back together or least not for a long time. Which is sad when they both seem to want it. Though now that Alana is sober, Marko has given in to his rage so I’m not sure that’s healthy either. We also catch back up with Gwendolyn and the Slave girl as they team up with The Will’s sister to get an antidote to save him. However, she dies after Slave girl tries to plan hero and when they explain that to The Will after reviving him ,he wants nothing to do with the two, only focused on rage which I’m sure will help him hunt down Hazel.
17. Avatar: The Last Airbender – Smoke and Shadow by Brian Konietzko, Michael Diante DiMartino, Gene Luen Yang, and Gurihirl
Tumblr media
I haven’t read the comic collection before this which explains the reunion of Zuko’s mom, so while I was sad I got spoiled, I can’t wait to read it to find out why her face was changed by a spirit. Still we get to see Fire Lord Zuko in action when an ancient Fire Lord story comes to life as children get captured by Kemurikage, a group of young women who also are helping the Fire Lord Ozai society to uprise against Zuko. Mai and Zuko are on the outs, but team up to solve the mystery with Aang’s help, who is also needed for his humor and level headedness. What I wasn’t expecting was to find that Azula is behind the Kemuirkage, so she definitely hasn’t changed her ways.
18. Doctor Who: Ground Zero by Scott Gray, Martin Geraghty, Alan Barnes, Gareth Roberts, and Adrian Salmon
Tumblr media
A mutli-doctor collection that eventually ties Sarah Jane, Tegan, Peri, and Ace together when an alien species is hell bent on hunting down the Doctor. Of course with the Seventh Doctor things are bound to get dark, but I was not prepared for how dark even though I’ve gotten used to comic Doctor-Who stories being darker than the show and audios. Still while it was fast pace and action packed, I also wasn’t prepared for this to be the canonical end to Ace (haha, just kidding, canon isn't real in DW). She’s the best and fought until the end, but I’m sad to learn that her story ends so tragically, making her the second companion to die while travelling with the Doctor.
19. Doctor Who: The Tenth Doctor Adventures Year Three #1: Breakfast at Tyranny’s by Nick Abadzis, Giorgia Sposito, Valeria Favoccia, Arianna Florean, and Hi-FI
Tumblr media
It’s been a while since I caught up with the Doctor and Gabby Gonzalez, but I was surprised to see that Gabby’s friend Cindy has also joined her as well as a powerful ancient being named Nubis (Based on the Eygptian Gods and apparently the son of Sutekh). They arrive in ancient China and learn of a plot that is formed by the cloning of Cindy, and while they sort it out, Cindy learns her heritage starts with her clones which makes her whole life a bit of a paradox. We also see that Gabby’s powers have grown and that’s starting to cause strain between her and the Doctor.
20. Doctor Who: The Tenth Doctor Adventures Year Three #2: Vortex Butterflies by Nick Abadzis, Giorgia Sposito, Iolanda Zanfardino, Arianna Florean, and Nicola Righi
Tumblr media
I’m glad to have read the next collection after the previous one because my suspicions about Gabby and the Doctor were right as they get pushed in this volume. The Doctor leaves Gabby and Cindy in London while he goes on the hunt of a mysterious anomaly that is causing time ripples. Thankfully he also clues in Sarah Jane Smith to look out for the two, but it gets harder as Gabby’s powers keep freaking out. Turns out the Doctor’s hunt leads him to a possible future Gabby whose powers are consuming the universe, but thanks to his friendship with Gabby he stops it and goes back to reassure Gabby that their friendship won’t ever devolve like that possible future.
0 notes
iphigeniarising · 1 year ago
Text
currently reading
Tumblr media
The Serpent's Coil - Elizabeth Silver COMPLETE Letters from Palestine - Kenneth Ring, Ghassan Abdullah
Tumblr media
Palestine, Israel and the U.S. Empire - Richard Becker COMPLETE Freedom is a Constant Struggle - Angela Davis COMPLETE
Tumblr media
Those Empty Eyes - Charlie Donlea DNF Alive: The True Story of the Andes Survivors - Piers Paul Read COMPLETE
1 note · View note
alphst · 2 years ago
Text
Guidewire Software Inc (GWRE) Q2 2023 Earnings Call Transcript
$GWRE Q2 2023 Earnings Call Transcript #earnings #markets #investing
Guidewire Software, Inc. (NYSE: GWRE) Q2 2023 earnings call dated Mar. 06, 2023 Corporate Participants: Alex Hughes — Vice President of Investor Relations Mike Rosenbaum — Chief Executive Officer Jeff Cooper — Chief Financial Officer Analysts: Dylan Becker — William Blair & Company — Analyst Kevin Kumar — Goldman Sachs — Analyst Rishi Jaluria — RBC Capital Markets — Analyst Kenneth…
Tumblr media
View On WordPress
0 notes
wheywheywheywhey · 2 years ago
Text
Using revealed preferences to estimate the Value of Travel Time to recreation sites
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 67 (2014) 58–70
Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jeem
Using revealed preferences to estimate the Value of Travel Time to recreation sites$$
Carlo Fezzi n, Ian J. Bateman, Silvia Ferrini CSERGE, School of Environmental Sciences, University of East Anglia, Norwich NR4 7TJ, UK
article info
Article history:
Received 31 July 2012 Available online 11 November 2013
Keywords:
Value of time Value of travel time savings Recreation demand models Revealed preferences Willingness to pay space
Introduction
abstract
The opportunity Value of Travel Time (VTT) is one of the most important elements of the total cost of recreation day-trips and arguably the most difficult to estimate. Most studies build upon the theoretical framework proposed by Becker (1965) by using a combination of revealed and stated preference data to estimate a value of time which is uniform in all activities and under all circumstances. This restriction is relaxed by DeSerpa's (1971) model which allows the value of saving time to be activity- specific. We present the first analysis which uses actual driving choices between open access and toll roads to estimate a VTT specific for recreation trips, thereby providing a value which conforms to both Becker's and DeSerpa's theoretical models. Using these findings we conduct a Monte Carlo simulation to identify generalizable results for subsequent valuation studies. Our results indicate that 3/4 of the wage rate provides a reasonable approximation of the average VTT for recreation trips, while the commonly implemented assumption of 1/3 of the wage rate generates downward biased results.
& 2013 The Authors. Published by Elsevier Inc. Open access under CC BY license.
Recreation demand models evaluate the welfare provided by a natural resource by combining information on respondent's characteristics, site visits and travel costs, which include both “out of pocket” costs (e.g. fuel and vehicle maintenance) and the opportunity cost of travel time. Feather and Shaw (1999), among others, show that this approach produces welfare estimates that can vary up to a factor of three depending on the approach used to calculate the Value of Travel Time (VTT). On these grounds, the large volume of trips made to open-access recreational sites every year places the VTT among the key parameters for environmental and public policy evaluation (e.g. National Survey on Recreation and the Environment, 2000; Natural England, 2010). Nevertheless, a consensus on the appropriate VTT to use in recreation demand modeling is still far from being achieved (Palmquist et al., 2010). This paper contributes to the debate by developing a novel
☆☆ We are grateful to the editor, Dan Phaneuf, and two anonymous referees for their comments, which helped improving the quality of the paper. Many thanks to Richard Carson, Chris Costello, Bob Deacon, Fabio Galeotti, Paolina Oliva, John Rose, Riccardo Scarpa, Marije Schaafsma, Kenneth Train and the participants of the 1st AERE Summer Conference, of the 18th EAERE Conference and of the 14th Occasional Workshop at UCSB for their helpful comments. Thanks also to Annagiulia Caleffi, Davide Dusi, Arturo Fanciulli, Tania Fiorini, Laure Higbee, Hanna Makinen, Cesare Molin, and Alan Torrisi for their help with the data collection. This research was supported by the LUCES Project (Project no.: 302290), funded by the European Commission under the Marie Curie International Outgoing Fellowship Programme, and by the SEER Project, funded by the ESRC (Funder ref.: RES-060-25-0063).
n Corresponding author. E-mail address: [email protected] (C. Fezzi).
0095-0696 & 2013 The Authors. Published by Elsevier Inc. Open access under CC BY license. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2013.10.003
C. Fezzi et al. / Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 67 (2014) 58–70 59
Revealed Preference (RP) method for estimating a VTT specific to leisure related journeys by modeling route choices to open- access recreation sites. In addition, it presents a Monte Carlo simulation testing simple and generalizable VTT assumptions for future environmental valuation studies.
VTT estimates are typically based on the theoretical models describing economic decisions under limited time allocation developed by Becker (1965) and DeSerpa (1971). Becker's framework assumes fixed time and monetary prices for each good and derives a (shadow) value of time which is uniform in all activities and under all circumstances. While this result can appear questionable, it allows the VTT to be derived by analyzing any decision in which individuals trade-off money for time. For example, Stated Preference (SP) questions concerning labor market choices have been often used in the environmental valuation literature to derive the VTT for recreation demand models (e.g. Bockstael et al., 1987; Feather and Shaw, 1999; Lew and Larson, 2005).
DeSerpa's theory can be thought as a generalization of Becker's framework. While in Becker's approach both money and time costs are fixed; in DeSerpa's model only the monetary costs are set, while the amount of time devoted to each activity is allowed to vary depending on individuals' preferences. This generalization allows the marginal utility of time (or the value of saving time) to vary among activities. Intuitively, the more an individual dislikes an activity, the higher should be her value of saving time in that specific task. While this new framework is certainly richer than Becker's original model, it has not yet been implemented in empirical recreation demand studies because of its strict data requirements. Ultimately, within DeSerpa's model, only decisions made by individuals when traveling to recreation sites can reveal their VTT for recreation. Nevertheless, estimating the VTT within a recreation demand model without including any further stated preference information (e.g. McConnell and Strand, 1981) is problematic because of the high correlation between the travel-cost and travel-time variables (e.g. Haab and McConnell, 2002; Small et al., 2005).
The main contribution of this paper is to resolve this issue by modeling the time–money trade-offs faced by individuals traveling to recreation sites when choosing between toll and free access roads, thereby providing an estimate of the VTT which is valid in both Becker's and DeSerpa's frameworks. Inferring VTT from toll road choices is particularly appealing, since saving travel time by avoiding congestions is the primary reason for the existence of toll roads and toll lanes. Indeed, using toll road decision to measure the VTT has a long history in transport economics (e.g. Bhat, 1995; Brownstone and Small, 2005; Small et al., 2005; Steimetz and Brownstone, 2005; Fosgerau et al., 2010). A recent paper by Wolff (in press) argues that this type of analyses may suffer from omitted variable bias and that modeling the relationship between vehicle speed and gasoline prices provides more robust VTT estimates. Ultimately, we believe that both approaches are valuable by having different strengths and weaknesses. While omitted variable bias is a potential concern for any applied econometric exercise, a key advantage of studying toll purchases is that they are explicitly related to time saving. In contrast, gas price is not the main variable affecting vehicle speed. More important factors are the level of traffic, the road and weather conditions, and even features which are very hard to measure such as the glare caused by the sun when it is low on the horizon (U.S. Department of Transport, 2008). Some of these impacts are difficult to account for (even by using fixed effects), without running into measurement-error problems.1 In addition, toll payment is highly visible trade-off between time and cost, while drivers are liable to see gasoline purchases (which are necessarily in past) as sunk costs and exhibit behaviors which do not confirm to economic rationality (Garland and Newport, 1991).
This analyses is distinguished from previous RP VTT studies by at least two additional features. First, rather than analyzing rush-hour commuters' choices on a single toll road section we consider respondents traveling from home to different recreation sites. This allows us to consider much larger time savings and longer trips. For example, the mean travel time saving in Small et al. (2005) is around 6 min, while our respondents, on average, can save more than 1 h of travel time by using toll roads. Second, by sampling respondents directly at the visited sites, we can focus on leisure related journeys and estimate a VTT specific to recreation. While there is considerable empirical evidence reporting significant changes in the VTT according to the purpose of the trip, the mode of travel or the level of congestion (e.g. Beesley, 1965; Makie et al., 2001; Brownstone and Small, 2005; Small et al., 2005; Fosgerau et al., 2010), to our knowledge is the first analysis which estimates a VTT specific to recreational trips using RP data on route choices.
Our case-study sites are three beaches located on the Italian Riviera Romagnola, whose road network is a mix of toll and free access roads. Toll roads allow faster speed and can save a significant amount of travel time, particularly for long- distance trips. However, they require higher monetary costs. By reconstructing respondents' routes to the beach we indentify individuals' trade-offs and their willingness-to-pay to save time when traveling to recreation sites. In line with previous literature (e.g. Lew and Larson, 2005; Small et al, 2005) we find that individuals differ substantially in their VTT, and that both observed and unobserved heterogeneity are significant. In order to investigate the robustness of a readily generalizable, yet empirically supported, VTT for future studies, we implement a Monte Carlo simulation showing that using a fixed fraction (about 3/4) of the average wage rate generates defensible welfare estimates. Such findings also suggest that the commonly adopted strategy of assuming a VTT equal to 1/3 of the respondent's wage rate (following Cesario, 1976)
1 Perhaps surprisingly, the U.S. Department of Transport (2008) estimates that the sun glare accounts for more than 60% of the road accidents attributable to adverse atmospheric conditions, causing every year more than three times the accidents attributable to fog, rain and snow put together. Its impact depends on a multitude of factors, such as the geometry and the orientation of the roadway and on the presence of buildings or trees blocking the sunlight. Since this effect also varies non-linearly with the time of the day and across the year, fixed-effects are not likely to be able to provide a solution, but by eliminating a lot of variation attributable to other sources, may actually exacerbate the omitted variable problem.
60 C. Fezzi et al. / Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 67 (2014) 58–70
produces a substantial and statistically significant downward bias in the resulting non-market benefit estimates. Results are robust in a variety of different model specifications.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. We first summarize DeSerpa’s model and its implications for the VTT for recreation. We then presents the data collection strategy and reports descriptive statistics and discuss the specification and estimation of the econometric models and reports the resulting VTT. We conclude by presenting the results of a Monte Carlo simulation investigating the effect that different VTT definitions have on nonmarket benefit estimates derived via recreation demand models.
DeSerpa's time allocation model and its implications for the VTT
Becker (1965) developed the first theoretical framework concerning individuals facing decisions subject to both money and time constraints. In his model the consumption of each good has fixed monetary and time costs, which allow the derivation of the shadow value of time. The subsequent generalization proposed by DeSerpa (1971) replaces the fixed time cost with time constraint inequalities, providing a more flexible and elegant framework in which the shadow value of time is replaced by a value of saving time specific to each activity.
Let xi (i1⁄41,...,k) indicate commodities or activities with associated monetary cost pi and consumption time ti, I is the available income and T is the available time (considering working time decisions as given).2 Individuals optimize both across consumption quantities and consumption times. Their utility-maximization problem can be written as follows:
max Uðx1; :::; xk; t1; :::; tkÞ; subject to the money and time constraints
∑ ki 1⁄4 1 p i x i 1⁄4 I ;
∑ ki 1⁄4 1 t i 1⁄4 T ;
tiZaixi; fori1⁄41;:::;k
ð1:1Þ
ð 1 : 2 Þ
ð 1 : 3 Þ
ð1:4Þ
Eqs. (1.4) are time consumption inequalities in which ai indicates the minimum amount of time necessary to consume one unit of xi. These restrictions can be interpreted as natural and institutional constraints related to the activities' characteristics. Examples are the length of a football game, the duration of a movie, minimum travel time due to speed limits and so on. While these constraints place a lower bound on the amount of ti consumed, individuals are still free to allocate more than the required time to any activity. The corresponding utility maximization problem can be represented with the following Lagrangian function:
L1⁄4Uðx1;:::;xk; t1;:::;tkÞþλðI∑ki1⁄41pixiÞþμðT0∑ki1⁄41tiÞþ∑ki1⁄41θiðtiaixiÞ The corresponding maximization conditions are
∂L=∂xi 1⁄4λpiþθiai; fori1⁄41;:::;k;
∂L=∂ti 1⁄4μθi; fori1⁄41;:::;k;
θiðtiaixiÞ1⁄40; fori1⁄41;:::;k:
ð2Þ
ð2:1Þ
ð2:2Þ
ð2:3Þ
Eq. (2.3) is the Kuhn–Tucker conditions corresponding to (1.4) and indicates that either ti1⁄4aixi (i.e. the time allocated to the consumption of xi is equal to the minimum amount needed and the constraint is binding) or θi1⁄40 (the individual allocates to the consumption of xi more time than it is strictly necessary).
The Lagrange multipliers λ and μ represent the marginal utility of money and the marginal utility of time. The ratio μ/λ is the shadow value of time. DeSerpa calls this quantity the “value of time as resource”, which derives from the fact that time is available only in a limited amount. However, its value cannot be measured since incrementing the amount of total time available makes little sense both according to this model and in reality. Therefore, this value is not the appropriate VTT for environmental valuation. Rather, the relevant VTT corresponds to the cost associated with spending time driving rather than doing another activity which generates greater utility. This is the “value of saving time from an activity” and can be calculated by dividing Eq. (2.2) by the marginal utility of money
∂LD;SR=∂ti 1⁄4μθi; fori1⁄41;:::;k: ð3Þ λλλ
This equation shows the marginal rate of substitution of ti for money, i.e. the value of time allocated to the consumption of xi. DeSerpa refers to this quantity the “value of time as a commodity”, which is equal to μ/λ only if θi1⁄40, i.e. when an individual allocates more than the required amount of time to the consumption of xi. On the other hand, when time spent in
2 We present the framework with labor-market decisions as given since, as discussed by Palmquist et al. (2010); this is the most appropriate framework for modeling short-run choices, such as those related to day-trip. However, as DeSerpa (1971) illustrates, a generalization including also working time decisions is straightforward.
C. Fezzi et al. / Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 67 (2014) 58–70 61
consuming xi is equivalent to the minimum required, the ratio θi/λ can be interpreted as the marginal value of relaxing the corresponding constrain or the “value of saving time from the activity”. This notion presupposes that time can be saved and transferred to another use which generates greater utility. In addition, the value of saved time is an activity-specific quantity since it derives from the parameter θi. Therefore, in this framework, the VTT for recreation cannot be inferred by measuring any time–money trade-offs other than those pertaining to driving decisions for recreation. As observing such trade-offs is uncommon, DeSerpa's framework has found no applications in empirical recreation demand studies so far.
Eq. (3) also shows that leisure activities are among the ones in which the allocated time is higher than the minimum required. For such activities the “value of saving time” is zero as utility cannot be increased by transferring time to any other use which generates greater utility. As θi1⁄40 and the “value of time as a commodity” are equal to the “value of time as a resource”. Therefore, time spent on site already has the maximum possible value and should not be included in the total cost of the trip because there is no alternative use which provides higher utility.
Empirical setting and data overview
Estimating a VTT for recreation consistent with DeSerpa's framework requires observations on individuals facing trade- offs involving money and driving time to recreation sites. In addition, this data needs to present relatively low correlation between travel times and travel costs, in order to obtain precise estimates of the effect of both variables on respondents' behavior. This last condition frequently fails to hold in practice. For example, recreation demand data are characterized by a very high collinearitiy between the travel-cost and travel-time variables, which significantly complicates the estimation of the VTT within standard RP travel cost models (e.g. Haab and McConnell, 2002; Small et al., 2005).
We address this correlation issue through a novel RP setting. Rather than modeling site choices as in standard recreation demand models, we analyze how individuals choose between different routes to travel to a given site, with each route option characterized by different travel time and monetary costs. The probability of person n choosing to visit site s and using route j can be written as the product of a marginal and a conditional probability as
Pnðs; jÞ 1⁄4 PnðsÞPnðj=sÞ
This probability can be analyzed using a nested logit model (McFadden, 1978), where the upper nest represents the beach choice and the lower nest represents the route choice. This does not necessarily imply a sequential decision process, but rather a separation of the total utility Wn(s,j) in a part which is constant across routes to the same beach (which we can envisage as a function of the beach characteristics, for example), indicated with Bn(s), and a part which varies with the route choice, function of travel time, monetary cost and route characteristics, which we indicate with Un(j). This can be written as:
Wnðs; jÞ 1⁄4 BnðsÞþUnðjÞþεn;j;
where εn,j is the error term with a generalized extreme value distribution and varies over respondent and route choice.3 Since we are interested in estimating the VTT for recreation and not in valuing the recreation sites per se, our focus is on the parameters in Un(j). As illustrated by Train (2009), these parameters can be consistently estimated by focusing on the lower nest, which represents the route decision choice conditional upon the beach choice, i.e. on Pn(j/s).4
For empirical estimation, our study takes advantage of the peculiar structure of the Italian road network, which is a mixture of toll and free-access roads, providing drivers with a rich array of different options for their travel costs and time. In Italy, most high-speed highways charge access fees proportional to the length of the highway used (with little variation on a per km basis) which are constant throughout the year and publicly available (e.g. on the site http://www.autostrade.it). These toll roads link all major Italian cities and can be accessed at specific stations, located roughly every 10–20 km, which connect them to the free road network. Typical toll roads consist of highways with two or three lanes in each direction, while the free-access roads have normally one or two lanes. Carpool lanes are not present in Italy. While tolls are proportional to the length of the highway used, the travel time savings can vary considerably, depending on the location of the stations relatively to the respondents' home and destination, and on the alternative routes available. This feature allows us to break-down the correlation between travel time and cost and to observe the choices of individuals facing very different time–money trade-offs.5
We choose as a case-study three beaches located on the Italian Riviera Romagnola: Rimini, Cesenatico and Igea-Marina. These are popular locations, attracting visitors from the entire Italian peninsula. Rimini is the most famous resort on the Riviera, and is also the most expensive, Cesenatico is slightly cheaper and visited both by families and young people, while
3 Another error-term which varies over respondent and beach choice can be included in the model, and as long as this component is uncorrelated with εn,j, it can be incorporated within Bn(s) without any loss of generality.
4 Modeling the joint probability P(s,j) could, in theory, increase the efficiency of the VTT estimates as also the site choice may contain information on the VTT as, for instance, individual may choose a location for the ability to get there fast. However, modeling P(s,j) in our empirical framework would require an extremely large choice set, possibly including all major beaches in Italy, with several routes to reach each one of them, and therefore, is practically unfeasible.
5 Extensive toll road systems are not specific to Italy. Studies similar to ours could be implemented in other European countries, such as France, Spain and Portugal, where toll roads are fairly common. Other countries characterized by the presence of toll roads are, for example, Mexico, China, Japan, Malaysia, Pakistan and India.
62 C. Fezzi et al. / Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 67 (2014) 58–70
Igea-Marina is the smallest and cheapest beach of the three and it is mainly visited by families. This diversity allows us to generate a heterogeneous sample, varying respondents' age, income and traveled distance. Furthermore, since the road network surrounding the three resorts consists of one toll highway and a variety of free access roads, the cost per minute of travel time saved is highly variable across our sample. As an illustration, Fig. 1 shows possible route options for two individuals traveling to Rimini, one living in Imola (top panel) and one living in Lavezzola (bottom panel). Both panels contrast the fastest free route (FFR), indicated by the dotted line, with the fastest toll route (FTR), represented as a solid line. In both examples the FTR enters the toll road at the “Imola” access station and exits at “Rimini South” access station. This route is both faster and more expensive than the FFR (the toll between these two stations is €5). However, the cost per unit travel time saved is very different. Travelers from Imola switching from the FFR to the FTR can save more than 1 h of travel time at a cost of about €5/h, while respondents from Lavezzola can only save about 20 min at the cost of almost €20/h, which is nearly four times more expensive. Given this heterogeneity, by sampling respondents living in different locations we are able to observe a wide range of time–cost trade-offs which allow us to obtain precise estimates of the VTT.
Since the main objective of this paper is to estimate the VTT specific to recreation trips, we survey individuals directly at the three sites under study. We interviewed individuals face-to-face during the months of August and September in the years 2010 and 2011, collecting information on their trip, route choice and socio-economic characteristics. The rate of non- response was very low, with less than 5% of those approached declining to be interviewed. Restricting the analysis to respondents who face both toll and open-access route options (and hence reveal trade-offs between money and travel time) yields a sample of 457 observations, including 155 (34% of the sample) individuals traveling for short, 1 day, visits to the beach, and 302 (66%) respondents staying at the resorts for longer holidays, some of them lasting more than a week. This further variation also allows us to test whether different planning horizons imply different values of time.
Since respondents are unlikely to know a priori the exact details of each alternative route, the relevant variables for this study are the expected travel time and cost. We assume that individuals have a feel for the distribution of the travel time and cost required by each possible route, based on their experience and on the information they can gather before the trip. This approach is standard in VTT RP studies (e.g. Brownstone and Small, 2005; Small et al., 2005; Steimetz and Brownstone,
Fig. 1. Possible routes and cost per time saved for two individuals living in different cities. Notes: the small inset map at the top represents the toll highway network in Italy. The upper panel shows two possible routes for a person living in Imola and traveling to Rimini, with the dotted line representing the fastest free route (FFR) and the solid line indicating the fastest route including a toll road (FTR). The lower panel represent the same route options for a person living in Lavezzola. Travel times calculated via the web site https://maps.google.com and fuel cost computed using the average fuel price in summer 2010 (€1.29/L). The toll cost is €5.
Table 1
Routes' descriptive statistics.
Route Time (min)
Mean Min FTR 137.8 28.0
FFR 233.9 35.0 FT1A 148.7 37.0 FT1B 144.7 35.0
Fuel cost (€) Toll cost (€) Mean Mean
C. Fezzi et al. / Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 67 (2014) 58–70
63
Include bypass
Mean
0.09 0.16 0.17 0.09 0.25
Notes: total number of within their choice-set (25% of the sample), whereas the other statistics refer to the full sample. FT1A is the fastest toll route by accessing the toll road one station after the one in FTR and FT1B is the fastest route by exiting the toll road one station before the one in FTR. Cost deflated to year 2010 by using gross domestic product deflator (source: the World Bank, www.worldbank.org).
2005). As a benchmark, we use the website https://maps.google.com to calculate a proxy for expected travel time. As shown in a previous research, such estimates are more appropriate and reliable than using ex-post perceptions of travel time (Steimetz and Brownstone, 2005). The fuel travel costs are determined by assuming an average consumption of 1 L/18 km and the average fuel price in summer 2010 (€1.29/L) and 2011 (€1.53/L) as provided by the Department of Economic Development (http://dgerm.sviluppoeconomico.gov.it).
Since the number of possible routes connecting two points on a road network is, at least in theory, infinite, we use some simple rules to indentify meaningful routes and thereby determine appropriate choice-sets for each respondent. A “core” choice-set for each respondent is defined by the following options: the FFR; the FTR; the FT1A (the fastest route accessing the toll road one station after that used in the FTR); and the FT1B (the fastest route exiting the toll road one station before the one in the FTR). These last two choices are relevant if the respondent's house or the beach is located in-between toll road stations, and entering/exiting the highway at the next/earlier station provides better time–money trade-off than either the FFR or the FTR. We finally include in each respondent's choice-set all the alternative routes chosen by individuals traveling from the same “outset area”. These outset areas are defined in terms of toll road use in order to group together individuals with the same entrance and exit according to the FTR (irrespective of whether or not they choose to use the toll road). Only 25% of the respondents belong to areas in which routes other than FFR, FTR, FT1A and FT1B are chosen.
Descriptive statistics for the route options are reported in Table 1. For most people (56%), the FTR is the preferred route, followed by the FFR (15%). Only 11% of the respondents choose a route outside the four options included in the “core” choice set. The variability in travel time is substantial. Considering the FTR, for example, travel time ranges from less than 30 min to more than 8 h. Considering monetary costs, a significant fraction is made up by toll fees. For instance, choosing the FTR instead of the FFR increases average travel costs by 40%. Columns 7–9 of Table 1 report the descriptive statistics of additional route characteristics which could influence respondents' route choices. These are represented via dummy variables which are respectively equal to one if the route includes a fast bypass road, a one-lane mountain road, and a scenic costal road. Non-toll bypass road is normally two lane roads which allow a relatively higher driving speed compared to the standard one-lane roads characterizing the free access Italian network. However, during peak hours they can become rapidly congested and cause considerable delays. Therefore their effect on route choice could vary with the general conditions of the road network. Single lane mountain routes (in our sample this includes those crossing the Appenini mountain range) are typically narrow and winding and hence potentially challenging and time-consuming. Such characteristics may negatively affect the choice probability of such roads. Finally, routes including scenic ocean vistas may reduce the dis-utility of driving or even provide positive utility. We define the latter routes as those which include sections less than 200 m from the sea. However, only a very small fraction of our respondents (7%) have routes with this characteristic in their choice-set, and therefore, we may not be able to estimate this last effect precisely.
To illustrate the different time–money trade-offs faced by the individuals in our sample, we calculate the cost per hour of travel time saved comparing the two most frequently chosen routes: FTR and FRR. For descriptive purposes, this ratio can be approximated by dividing the toll by the difference in travel time, since fuel costs are typically very similar between the two options. The distribution of the toll cost per hour of time saved is represented by the histogram illustrated in Fig. 2. While most individuals face toll costs between €5/h and €10/h, there is considerable variability in trade-offs, with a significant proportion of respondents facing very high potential fees, rising to more than €50/h.
Descriptive statistics for all the other variables included in the study are reported in Table 2. Driver's income, age and the number of passengers show great heterogeneity although most drivers are male (71%) and most passengers are older than 16, with an average of 2.3 adults per party. By using the common assumption of 2000 work hours per year (e.g. Haab and McConnell, 2002; Hynes et al., 2009), we calculate respondents' average gross hourly wage rate as being about €12/h. This corresponds to a monthly income of about €2100, which is similar to the average level of €2054 reported by the Italian Statistical Institute (Istat, http://dati.istat.it/?lang=en) for the year 2011. Our sample, therefore, represents well the average income of the entire country. Finally, the last three columns compare respondents across route-choices, showing that our
Max
495.0 763.0 498.0 502.0
16.22 15.49 16.35 16.32 17.25
11.26 0.00 10.29 10.76 9.35
Include mountain road
Mean
0.02 0.09 0.02 0.02 0.01
Include scenic road
Mean
0.00 0.07 0.00 0.00 0.00
% Chosen
56 15 14
4 11
Other routes 174.2
84 418.0
observations equal
to 457. The statistics
of the “other routes” category
refers only to those FTR is the fastest tolls route, FFR is the fastest free route,
respondents who has these options
64 C. Fezzi et al. / Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 67 (2014) 58–70
Fig. 2. Histogram of toll cost per hour of travel time saved. Notes: histogram of the toll cost per hour of travel time saved, which is defined as the ratio between (a) the toll and (b) the difference in time between the fastest toll route and the fastest free route for our sample (N1⁄4457). Note that nine respondents have a toll–time ratio higher than €50/h and lie outside the range of the plotted values.
Table 2
Respondents' descriptive statistics.
Personal income (€1000/month) Age (years) Gender People in the car
4 16 Years old o 16 Years old
x
s^ðxÞ Min 1.33 0.25
Max x (y1⁄4FTR) 11.20 2.15
x (y1⁄4FFR) 2.33
43.38 0.29 2.54 2.07 0.47
x (y1⁄4other) 1.92
40.51 0.26 2.92 2.27 0.65
2.11 40.70
76.00 40.00 0.30
12.17 18.00 0.29 0.45 01
2.85 1.13 17 2.27 0.86 17 0.59 0.84 04
2.89 2.32 0.57
Notes: x indicates the sample mean, and s^ðxÞ is the sample standard deviation. The y1⁄4FTR/FFT/other indicates the subsample of respondents who choose respectively the fastest tool route (n1⁄4256), the fastest free route (n1⁄469), and all other routes (n1⁄4133). The statistics on age and income (before tax) refer to the driver. Income deflated to year 2010 by using gross domestic product deflator (source: the World Bank, www.worldbank.org).
sample is essentially well balanced in that the average values of the socio-economic characteristics are basically the same for individuals choosing either FTR, FFR or any other route.
The econometric model
The empirical specification
As illustrated in the previous section, we estimate the VTT by focusing on the route choice as conditional on the recreation site choice. Assuming that utility is linear in income, and for simplicity, eliminating that portion of utility which is constant among route alternatives, Bn(s), we can write the (dis-)utility which person n (n1⁄41,...,N) receives from choosing route j (j1⁄41,...,J) as
UnðjÞ 1⁄4 Un;j 1⁄4 λncn;j þθntn;j þqj þεn;j; ð4Þ
where tn,j is the route time, cn,j is the route cost (including both toll and fuel cost, which we assume are equally shared among all adults in the car), θn is the marginal (dis-)utility of spending time driving rather than in other activities which generate greater utility and λn is the marginal utility of money. Both coefficients correspond to the parameters of DeSerpa's model reported in Eq. (2), and are allowed to vary across respondents. Furthermore, qj includes all observed characteristics of the route which have some implications for the choice and the residual term εn,j encompasses the unobserved characteristics of both the respondent and the route. This residual component is assumed to be distributed as a type I extreme value with scale parameter kn. Respondent n chooses route j if Un,j4Un,i 8i. Finally, the parameter of travel time, while is allowed to differ across respondents, does not vary per route option. Therefore, while we encompass route
C. Fezzi et al. / Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 67 (2014) 58–70 65
characteristics through the term qj, we also assume that driving produces the same (dis-)utility per unit of time regardless of the type of road traveled.6
As shown in Eq. (3), in this model the relevant VTT for recreation is the ratio of the marginal (dis-)utility of time spent driving to the marginal utility of money
VTTn 1⁄4 ∂Un;j=∂tn;j 1⁄4 θn : ð5Þ ∂Un;j=∂cn;j λn
As dividing or multiplying utility does not affect behavior, we can divide (4) by the scale parameter obtaining an error term with the same variance for all respondents
Un;j 1⁄4 λn cn;j þ θn tn;j þ qj þωn;j: ð6Þ kn kn kn
Train and Weeks (2005) refer to this equation as a model specified in “preference space”. Unobserved heterogeneity in preferences can be encompassed by specifying a probability distribution for the time and cost coefficients and estimating the model as a mixed logit (e.g. Train, 1998, 2009). Among the most commonly applied distributions are the normal, the log–normal, the uniform and the triangular. However, recent findings indicate that models with preference parameters distributed according to these simple probability densities generate Willingness to Pay (WTP) distributions (in our case VTT distributions) with counter-intuitive features, such as excessively long tails or non-finite moments (e.g. Scarpa et al., 2008). A possible solution is to define a cost coefficient which is constant across respondents (e.g. Revelt and Train, 1998). This assumption allows the WTP distribution to match that of the time coefficient. However, this restriction is somehow counter- intuitive since, as shown in Eq. (6), a fixed cost coefficient (λn1⁄4λ, 8n) implies that the standard deviation of the residual term εj,n is the same for all respondents (kn1⁄4k, 8n). If violated, this latter assumption will induce biased inference by erroneously attributing variation in scale to variation in WTP.
Train and Weeks (2005) resolve this issue by rewriting the model in what they define as being the WTP representation, which, in our context, we refer to as VTT space. Defining λn 1⁄4 λn/kn and qn;j 1⁄4 qj/λn, we can rewrite (6) as
Un;j 1⁄4 λn1⁄2cn;j þVTTntn;j þqn;jþωn;j: ð7Þ
In this parameterization the variation in VTT is independent from the variation in scale, which is encompassed in the cost coefficient λn. Another advantage of this approach is that we can directly specify a distribution for the VTT rather than generating it numerically as a ratio. In addition, we can include some observed factors within the specification of the VTT (e.g. VTTn1⁄4α0,nþα1incn, with incn1⁄4income of respondent n) and directly test their significance with standard inference (e.g. Thiene and Scarpa, 2009). The appeal of the “WTP space” parameterization over the traditional “preference space” specification for VTT estimates is confirmed by Hensher and Green (2011), among others.
Model (7) is a non-linear in parameters mixed logit model and its estimation can be implemented via Simulated Maximum Likelihood (SML) (Train, 2009; Scarpa et al., 2008). Conditional on the values of the random parameters γn1⁄4{λn, VTTn}, the probability of person n choosing route j can be written as the following standard logit formula (McFadden, 1974):
pnðjjγnÞ 1⁄4 expðVn;jÞ ; ð8Þ ∑Ji 1⁄4 1 expðVn;iÞ
where Vn,i1⁄4Un,i–ωn,i. The unconditional probability is given by the integral of (8) over all possible values of γn, weighted by their density
Z
pnðjÞ 1⁄4 where g(.) is the joint probability distribution function of the random parameters. Indicating with yn the dummy variable
identifying the route chosen by respondent n, the log-likelihood function to be maximized is ln L 1⁄4 ∑Nn 1⁄4 1pnðjÞyn: ð9Þ
Rather than directly maximizing the likelihood (9), we approximate the integral over γn via simulation. This approach consists of taking draws from the distribution of the random parameters, calculating pn(j) for every draw and then averaging the results. This SML estimator is consistent, asymptotically normal and efficient for an increasing number of draws (Train, 2009). Estimation is implemented in the free software R (R Development Core Team, 2008) using the Nelder–Mead (1965) maximization algorithm and 50 Halton draws per person (as per Train, 2009). The R code and the data used in this study are available on the corresponding author webpage.
6 In line with most RP analyses we do not consider the effect of possible road congestion, which is commonly referred to as the “travel time reliability” and typically investigated using SP data (e.g. Li et al., 2010) or by combining RP and SP informations (e.g. Small et al., 2005). However, congested roads are not likely to be an issue for our estimates, since most of the respondents (around 90%) did not report any significant road traffic. In addition, only a small fraction of the interviewees who actually encountered road congestion adjusted their route accordingly, typically abandoning congested highway for smaller roads. We eliminated these individuals (about 1% of the sample) from the analysis since their traveled route differed from the one they had planned a priori based on expected travel cost and travel time.
pnðjjγnÞgðγnÞdγn;
66 C. Fezzi et al. / Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 67 (2014) 58–70 Table 3
Model estimates and corresponding VTT.
Time s.e. (Time) Cost s.e. (Cost) FTR FFR Bypass Scenery Mountain Time n gender Time n d_ageZ60 Time n p_inc Time n one_day Log-likelihood Pseudo R2 Mean WTP (€/h)
 3.031nnn  3.533nnn
 580.06 0.13 8.58
(0.361) (0.543)
0.858nnn  3.533nnn
 580.06 0.13 8.58
(0.072) (0.543)
0.835nnn
 2.996nnn
(0.107) (0.549) (0.089)
(0.121) (0.051) (1.461) (0.888) (0.047) (0.073) (0.063)
Preference space
Model A1 base model
VTT space
Model A2 base model
Model B route characteristics
Model C route and respondent characteristics
0.700nnn (0.136)
3.116nnn (0.562)
 0.394nnn (0.083) 0.440nnn (0.113) 0.234nn (0.112)
0.225 (0.211) 0.629nnn (0.221) 0.039 (0.108)
0.305nnn (0.119) 0.091n (0.053) 0.138 (0.141)
Model D unobserved heterogeneity (Gaussian)
0.777nnn
0.218nnn  6.626nnn 3.396nnn 0.166nnn  0.263nnn
Model E unobserved heterogeneity (Triangular)
0.712nnn (0.122)
6.166nnn (1.263)
0.175nnn (0.047) 0.262nnn (0.073) 0.153nnn (0.065)
0.232 (0.171) 0.537nnn (0.188) 0.052 (0.088)
0.302nnn (0.119) 0.092nn (0.036) 0.054 (0.107)
 485.98 0.27 9.16
 0.425nnn 0.416nnn (0.110) 0.243n (0.144)
0.151nnn 0.153 (0.171) 0.549nnn (0.187) 0.016 (0.093)
0.218 (0.266) 0.612nnn (0.233)
 500.31 0.25 8.35
 0.321nnn (0.107) 0.085n (0.048)
0.003 (0.106)  483.33
Notes: travel cost expressed in €10 (e.g. €1001⁄410), travel time in hours, and gross income in €1000/year (e.g. €20,000/year1⁄420). n 1⁄4 Significance at the 10% level. nn 1⁄4 Significance at the 5% level. nnn 1⁄4 Significance at the 1% level.
Estimation results
The results provided by different model specifications are reported in Table 3. As a benchmark, the first column reports a standard conditional logit model in preference space with only route time and cost as choice attributes (Model A1). The estimated VTT is about €8.6/h which corresponds to roughly 70% of the average wage rate. This is close to the value reported by Steimetz and Brownstone (2005) for non-work related trips ($11/h). For illustrative purposes, Model A2 in the second column reports the reparameterization of Model A1 in VTT space. Since the two models do not include any random parameters, they yield exactly the same VTT estimate and log-likelihood. All the other models in Table 3 are estimated directly in VTT space. Model B, reported in the third column, extends the base specification by including route characteristics. The coefficients show that, given the same cost and time, the fastest free route (FFR) and the fastest toll route (FTR) are much more likely to be chosen than those other routes containing different combinations of toll and free roads. This reflects the fact that FFR and FTR are the two most cognitively straightforward routes and those which, for example, can be automatically selected on standard satellite navigators. In contrast, alternative routes, such as FT1A or FT1B, require greater knowledge of the area and its road network. In addition, routes including tracts of bypass roads are more likely to be chosen than other routes. Since bypasses are typically congested in peak hours but offer fast driving options during off-peak, this result suggests that the trips in our sample are typically carried out outside peak time. As expected, one lane mountain routes are considerably less likely to be chosen than other routes because of their difficult driving conditions. Finally, the dummy variable identifying scenic costal routes is not significantly different from zero (although this result might reflect the low number of respondents with such options within their choice sets).
Model C includes both route and respondent characteristics. In line with our expectations and consistent with the results of previous work (e.g. Deacon and Sonstelie, 1985; Steimetz and Brownstone, 2005; Small et al, 2005), income has a positive effect. With every additional €10,000 of gross yearly salary the VTT increases, on average, by €0.9/h. In addition, the VTT of respondents older than 60 years is, on average, about 30% lower than that of younger age groups. This finding can be explained by the high proportion of retired workers in this age class who, by having more free time, may also present a lower VTT. Finally, our estimates indicate that neither the gender of the driver nor the length of holiday have any significant influence on the value of saving travel time.7
Models D and E relax the constant scale parameter assumption and introduce unobserved taste heterogeneity. In Model D both the cost and the VTT parameters are assumed to be normally distributed and in Model E they are assumed to follow a triangular distribution in order to restrict the effect of increases in costs and travel time to always have a negative effect on utility.8 The results of the normally distributed random effects model (Model D) confirm findings in the literature (e.g. Lew
7 We also tested if VTT changes with the length of the trip, by allowing the time parameter to change for short (FTR timer60 min), medium (60 minoFTR timer150 min) and long (FTR time4150 min) trips. These additional parameters were not statistically significant.
8 Another approach to implement this restriction is to assume a log–normal distribution. However, similarly to others (e.g. Small et al., 2005), we were unable to obtain convergence with that specification.
 492.83 0.26 0.28 9.26 9.35
C. Fezzi et al. / Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 67 (2014) 58–70 67
and Larson, 2005) in showing significant unobserved heterogeneity, with both random parameters standard errors being highly statistically significant. Considering an interval equal to plus and minus one standard error, the VTT for recreation varies from about €7.7/h to €11.5/h, with an average of €9.4/h. Also the triangular specification (Model E) provides a better fit than the fixed effect one (Model C), while having the same number of parameters. This model estimates the average VTT to be around €9.2/h.
Overall, starting from a base model with only time and monetary cost parameters, and in sequence, including routes' characteristics, respondents' characteristics and unobserved heterogeneity considerably improves the model fit (the pseudo R2 more than doubles going from 0.13 to 0.27) but does not significantly change our findings. In fact, our VTT estimates are remarkably stable, remaining between €8.4/h and €9.4/h, or around 70–80% of the wage rate across all specifications. As introducing both observed and unobserved heterogeneity does not significantly affect the VTT parameter, any potential bias arising from possible omitted variables should also not be of strong concern for our results. In addition, although our study focuses on the VTT for recreation, our empirical estimates fall within the lower end of the range reported by previous RP studies on the VTT for generic road trips (e.g. Deacon and Sonstelie (1985) and Small et al. (2005), respectively report a VTT of about 80% and 93% of the wage rate). Overall, this result aligns our findings with the earlier literature, as both intuition and prior research (e.g. Steimetz and Brownstone, 2005) indicate that non-work related trips should present a (slightly) lower VTT than business-related ones. This feature provides supporting evidence on the ability of our estimates to represent other countries and contexts.
Finally, while income is a significant factor in explaining the VTT, we also find strong unobserved heterogeneity, with estimated person-specific VTTs ranging from less than 50% to more than 100% of the personal wage depending on respondents' tastes and attitudes towards driving. Therefore, our findings agree with those of Lew and Larson (2005) and Small et al. (2005), which show that both observed and unobserved sources of heterogeneity are important in VTT elicitation. The next section analyzes which assumptions can be implemented in empirical studies in which VTT estimation is not feasible. To do so, we undertake a simple Monte Carlo simulation comparing some of the options which have been implemented so far in the recreation demand modeling literature.
Testing alternative VTT assumptions in recreation demand studies: a Monte Carlo simulation
Previous studies (e.g. McKean et al., 1995; Feather and Shaw, 1999) show that welfare estimates derived via recreation demand models are highly sensitive to the assumed VTT. While our analysis employs a rich dataset on route options, it is not always possible to estimate person-specific VTTs within every recreation demand study. When this estimation is unfeasible, which is the appropriate VTT to use? In order to answer this question, we design a simple Monte Carlo simulation based on our data and estimates. We proceed in two steps. First, we generate site-visits using the person-specific VTT predicted by our best fitting model, which includes both observed and unobserved heterogeneity. This produces the typical data that a recreation survey would collect. Second, we estimate competing recreation demand models employing different VTT assumptions and contrast them with the “true” model based on the unobserved, person-specific VTT used to generate the data. Comparing welfare estimates across models allow us to draw some guidelines for applied recreation demand research.
For simplicity, and in order to simulate one of the most common valuation frameworks, we follow McKean et al. (1995) in focusing our simulation on a single-site model. We choose the beach of Cesenatico, for which we have 247 survey respondents. For each individual in this subsample, we calculate the VTT according to Model D in Table 3, which encompasses both observed and unobserved heterogeneity with normally distributed random parameters. We estimate person-specific parameters following the approach outlined by Train (2009). Specifically, we derive the distribution of the VTT for each respondent as conditional to the data by using Bayes' rule
hðVTTnjj;znÞ1⁄4 pnðjjzn;VTTnÞNðVTTnjΩÞ; ð10Þ pn ðjjzn ; ΩÞ
where VTTn is the value of travel time for respondent n, j indicates the chosen option, zn represents all the explanatory variables in the model (i.e. income, age, and gender and route characteristics) and Ω are the parameter estimates, including the mean and standard error of the random parameters. The function h(.) is the distribution of VTTn given the observables, N(.) is the Gaussian probability distribution of VTTn given the parameters, pn(j|zn,VTTn) is the probability of the observed choice given the value of time and the explanatory variables, and pn(j|zn,Ω) is the integral of pn(j|zn,VTTn) on the parameter space. This denominator is a constant, and therefore, h(.) is proportional to the numerator. As suggested by Train (2009), we calculate the expected value of h (.) by simulation, randomly generating 1000 draws of VTTn from the normal population density N(VTTn|Ω) and computing their weighted mean, with weights proportional to pn(j|zn,VTTn).
After calculating individual-specific VTTs, we generate, for each respondent, the number of visits (Rn) to Cesenatico beach using a simple trip-simulation function specified with the following exponential form:
Rn 1⁄4 expðβ0 β1TCn þunÞ; ð11Þ
with TCn 1⁄4 total round-trip cost from the respondent's home to the beach (including both fuel cost and VTTn and considering the least-cost route), un1⁄4i.i.d. Gaussian residual term, and β0 and β1 are the functional form parameters. This Data Generating Process (DGP) simulates the information that a standard single-site recreation survey would collect (e.g. McKean et al., 1995; Haab and McConnell, 2002).
68 C. Fezzi et al. / Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 67 (2014) 58–70 Table 4
Monte Carlo simulation: welfare estimates using different VTT. Mean WTP (€)
5% Quantile of WTP (€) 0.57 (0.47, 0.71)
0.18 (0.14, 0.22) 0.44 (0.36, 0.54) 0.74 (0.60, 0.92) 0.61 (0.50, 0.76) 0.60 (0.45, 0.74)
95% Quantile of WTP (€) 11.47 (10.26, 12.83)
3.56 (3.18, 3.99)
8.91 (7.9, 9.98) 14.81 (13.25, 16.59) 12.39 (11.07, 13.89) 12.06 (10.82, 13.52)
True VTTn VTTn 1⁄4 0 VTTn 1⁄4 1/3wn VTTn1⁄4wn VTTn 1⁄4 3/4wn VTTn 1⁄4 3/4w
9.29 (8.61, 10.10) 2.88 (2.67, 3.13) 7.21 (6.68, 7.85) 11.99 (11.11, 13.05) 10.03 (9.28, 10.04) 9.78 (9.06, 10.64)
Notes: results generated with 5000 Monte Carlo repetition, wn indicates the person specific wage rate and w indicates the sample mean wage rate. In brackets is the 95% confidence intervals.
We can now estimate simple models explaining the simulated visits as a function of the total round-trip cost, which we calculate by using different VTT definitions in order to assess their impacts on WTP estimates. We maintain the exponential form used in the DGP and estimate the following model:
lnðRnÞ 1⁄4 b0 b1TCn þεn; ð12Þ
where the TCn is the round-trip cost which we compute considering the following VTT definitions: (a) the “true” person- specific value used in the DGP (i.e. TCn 1⁄4TCn), (b) zero, (c) 1/3 of the respondent wage rate (Cesario, 1976), (d) the respondent full wage rate, (e) 3/4 (or 75%) of the respondent wage rate and (f) 3/4 of the average wage rate. The last two definitions use the average fraction of the salary estimated on our data but differ in that for option (e) the VTT is proportional to each person's salary while option (f) uses a “one size fits all” approach by assigning the same VTT to all respondents, including those who are currently unemployed.
As consumer surplus we use the WTP of access as given by Haab and McConnell (2002) Z1 ^^ yn
WTP1⁄4 expðb0þb1cÞdc1⁄4^ ; ð13Þ TCn b1
where the “hat” indicates the parameter estimates of (12) obtained via ordinary least squares and all other symbols are defined as previously.
We simulate several demand equations varying the intercept (b0) and slope (b1) and the standard error of the trip-generation function to compare VTT assumptions in different settings. Since findings remained consistent across all specifications, for ease of exposition we report only the results obtained using “average” parameter values within the explored DGP space, i.e. setting b01⁄44, b11⁄40.5 and s.e.(un)1⁄40.5 in Eq. (11). These values generate a number of trips per respondent varying from almost 0 to around 100.
Results obtained from 5000 Monte Carlo repetitions comparing WTP estimates using our six different VTT definitions are presented in Table 4 and in the box-plots in Fig. 3. In line with previous literature, WTP estimates vary considerably depending on how the VTT is determined. The first row/box-plot reports the WTP estimates obtained by using the “true” unobserved person-specific VTT used to generate the data. The mean WTP is around €9.3, but there is considerable variability between respondents, with the 5th percentile being only €0.6 and the 95th almost €11.5. The second row reports the estimates obtained by assuming that travel time has no value. As expected, this definition generates a significantly lower consumer surplus, roughly reducing the average WTP of a factor of three to about €2.9. As shown in the third row, the common assumption that VTT is equal to 1/3 of the wage rate (as per Cesario (1976), and in numerous other studies) also produces downwardly biased estimates, with an average of about €7.2. On the other hand, the results presented in the fourth row show that assuming that the VTT is equal to the full wage substantially inflates WTP values, the average being about €12, which is higher than the 95th percentile calculated from the “true” VTT.
The best approximation of the true WTP is provided by adopting the assumption that VTT is 3/4 of the wage rate, reported in the last two rows of Table 4, with means and percentiles only slightly higher than the ones used in the DGP. As shown by comparing the box-plots in Fig. 3, these are the only assumptions which produce 95% confidence intervals which include the mean of the WTP calculated using the true VTT value. In addition, despite salary being a significant factor in the simulation of the person-specific VTT data, assuming the VTT to be 3/4 of average wage rate produces slightly better estimates than defining the VTT equal to 3/4 of the personal wage rate. This may look like a surprising result, but it can be explained by the strong importance that unobserved factors, such as attitudes towards driving, play in determining the VTT. As these factors cannot be observed and do not necessarily vary proportionally with income, using a “one size fits all” approach by approximating the true VTT with a value which is a fraction of the average salary can be a simple and yet effective strategy for obtaining sensible WTP estimates for valuing recreation sites. Another advantage of this approach is that it provides VTT estimates for both employed and unemployed respondents, rather than implicitly assuming that those outside the workforce have zero VTT as in conventional analyses. As shown by Feather and Shaw (1999), among others, this latter approach can downwardly bias WTP values significantly if a large proportion of respondents are unemployed.
C. Fezzi et al. / Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 67 (2014) 58–70 69
Fig. 3. Average WTP estimates. Notes: confidence intervals for the mean WTP of access, calculated with 5000 bootstrap repetitions. The gray box indicates the 1st and 3rd quartile and the wishers the 95% confidence interval. The symbol wn indicates the person specific wage rate and w indicates the sample mean wage rate.
Obviously, assuming the same VTT for all respondents still remains a second-best strategy, which should be implemented only when investigating individual-specific VTTs is not a feasible option.
Conclusions and further research
We introduce a novel RP setting to estimate the VTT for recreation trips based on traveling choices between alternative routes characterized by different time and monetary costs. Compared with previous studies, which use labor market choices (e.g. Feather and Shaw, 1999; Lew and Larson, 2005) or household maintenance options (Palmquist et al., 2010) to estimate the value of time, our analysis has the important advantage of being based on actual travel-choice decisions for recreation. Therefore, it provides a VTT which is appropriate in both Becker's (1965) model of economic decisions with time constraints and in the subsequent generalization by DeSerpa (1971), while earlier analyses are valid only within the first and more restrictive framework.
The average VTT of our sample is between €8.4/h and €9.4/h, or around 3/4 of the average wage rate; a value which is in the lower end of the range identified by previous RP studies on the VTT of generic road trips, reassuring us on the external validity of our results. In addition, our estimates confirm previous findings (e.g. Lew and Larson, 2005) in that individuals differ substantially in how they value travel time to recreational sites, and that both observed and unobserved characteristics are important in determining that value. For instance, VTT increases with income and decreases for those who are older than 60 years, probably reflecting the higher proportion of retired people with fewer commitments in this age group. As our results remain robust in a variety of model specifications (including both observed and unobserved heterogeneity), arguably any potential bias arising from possible omitted variables should also not be of strong concern for our estimates.
As shown in previous studies (e.g. Feather and Shaw, 1999), welfare estimates from recreation demand models are highly sensitive to the assumed VTT. An earlier work (e.g. Lew and Larson, 2005; Palmquist et al., 2010) included SP questions on labor market or household maintenance decisions within the standard RP recreation survey to recover individual-specific VTTs for recreation. Another feasible option could be to add SP choices on alternative routes to reach the recreation sites providing respondents with different money–travel time trade-offs. However, further research is necessary to test if values provided by this SP approach conform to RP estimates, since findings to date seem to indicate a significant gap between SP and RP estimates of VTT (e.g. Brownstone and Small, 2005; Small et al., 2005).
Finally, our Monte Carlo simulation shows which simple assumptions can be implemented in applied recreation demand models when it is not feasible to estimate person-specific VTT measures. Assuming VTTs which are either zero or 1/3 of the wage rate (as suggested by Cesario (1976), and implemented in many subsequent studies) clearly produce downward biased estimates, while defining the VTT to be equal to the full wage rate somewhat overestimates values. In our case-study we find that ignoring respondent heterogeneity and setting VTT equal to 3/4 of the average wage in the sample provide defensible results which, on average, are not significantly different from those obtained using the “true”, unobserved, VTT used to generate the data.
70 C. Fezzi et al. / Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 67 (2014) 58–70 References
Beesley, M.E., 1965. The value of time spent in travelling: some new evidence. Economica 32, 174–185. Becker, G.S., 1965. A theory of the allocation of time. Economic Journal 75, 493–517. Bhat, C., 1995. A heteroscedastic extreme value model of intercity travel mode choice. Transportation Research 29, 471–483. Bockstael, N.E., Strand, I.E., Hanemann, W.M., 1987. Time and the recreation demand model. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 69, 293–302. Brownstone, D., Small, K.A., 2005. Valuing time and reliability: assessing the evidence from road pricing demonstrations. Transportation Research Part A 39,
279–293. Cesario, F.J., 1976. The value of time in recreation benefit studies. Land Economics 52, 32–41. Deacon, R.T., Sonstelie, J., 1985. Rationing by waiting and the value of time: results from a natural experiment. Journal of Political Economy 93, 627–647. DeSerpa, A., 1971. A theory of the economics of time. Economic Journal 81, 828–846. Feather, P.M., Shaw, W.A., 1999. Estimating the cost of leisure time for recreation demand models. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management
38, 49–65. Fosgerau, M., Hjorth, K., Lyk-Jensen, S.P., 2010. Between-mode-differences in the value of travel time: self-selection or strategic behaviour? Transportation
Research Part D 15, 370–381. Garland, H., Newport, S., 1991. Effects of absolute and relative sunk costs on the decision to persist with a course of action. Organizational Behavior and
Human Decision Processes 48, 55–69. Haab, T.C., McConnell, K.E., 2002. In: Valuing Environmental and Natural Resources: The Econometrics of Non-Market ValuationEdward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK. Hensher, D.A., Green, W.H., 2011. Valuation of travel time savings in WTP and preference space in the presence of taste and scale heterogeneity. Journal of
Transport Economics and Policy 45, 505–525. Hynes, S., Hanley, N., O’Donoghue, C., 2009. Alternative treatments of the cost of time in recreational demand models: an application to whitewater
kayaking in Ireland. Journal of Environmental Management 90, 1014–1021. Lew, K.L., Larson, D.M., 2005. Accounting for stochastic shadowvalues of time in discrete-choice recreation demand models. Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management 50, 341–361. Li, Z., Hensher, D.A., Rose, J.M., 2010. Willingness to pay for travel time reliability in passenger transport: a review and some new empirical evidence.
Transportation Research Part E 46, 384–403. Makie, P.J., Jara-Díaz, S., Fowkes, A.S., 2001. The value of time savings in evaluation. Transportation Research Part E 37, 91–106. McConnell, K.E., Strand, I., 1981. Measuring the cost of time in recreation demand analysis: an application to sportfishing. American Journal of Agricultural
Economics 63, 153–156. McFadden, D., 1974. Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice behavior. In: Zarembka, P. (Ed.), Frontiers in Econometrics, Academic Press, New York. McFadden, D., 1978. Modeling the choice of residential location. In: Karlqvist, A., Lundqvist, L., Snickars, F., Weibull, J. (Eds.), Spatial Interaction Theory and
Planning Models, North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 75–96. McKean, J.R., Johnson, M.D., Walsh, R.G., 1995. Valuing time in travel cost demand analysis: an empirical investigation. Land Economics 71, 96–105. National Survey on Recreation and the Environment, 2000. NSRE 2000, Round 1 Report. Available from: 〈http://www.srs.fs.usda.gov/recreation/nsre.html〉
(accessed July 2012). Natural England, 2010. Monitor of engagement with the natural environment: the national survey on people and the natural environment. MENE Technical
Report NECR050. Available from: 〈http://naturalengland.etraderstores.com/NaturalEnglandShop/NECR050〉 (accessed December 2010). Nelder, J.A., Mead, R., 1965. A simplex algorithm for function minimization. Computer Journal 7, 308–313. Palmquist, R.B., Phaneuf, D.J., Smith, V.K., 2010. Short run constraints and the increasing marginal value of time in recreation. Environmental and Resource
Economics 46, 19–41. Revelt, D., Train, K., 1998. Mixed logit with repeated choices. Review of Economics and Statistics 80, 647–657. R Development Core Team, 2008. R: A Language and Environment for Statistical Computing. R Foundation for Statistical Computing, Vienna, Austria.
〈http://www.r-project.org〉. Scarpa, R., Thiene, M., Train, K., 2008. Utility in willingness to pay space: a tool to address confounding random scale effects in destination choice to the
Alps. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 90, 994–1010. Small, K.A., Winston, C., Yan, J., 2005. Uncovering the distribution of motorists' preferences for travel time and reliability. Econometrica 73, 1367–1382. Steimetz, S.S.C., Brownstone, D., 2005. Estimating commuters' “value of time” with noisy data: a multiple imputation approach. Transportation Research
Part B 39, 865–889. Thiene, M., Scarpa, R., 2009. Deriving and testing efficient estimates of WTP distributions in destination choice models. Environmental and Resource
Economics 44, 379–395. Train, K.E., 1998. Recreation demand models with taste difference over people. Land Economics 74, 185–194. Train, K.E., 2009. In: Discrete choice methods with simulationSecond Ed. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Train, K.E., Weeks, M., 2005. Discrete choice models in preference space and willing-to-pay space. In: Scarpa, R., Alberini, A. (Eds.), Applications of
Simulation Methods in Environmental and Resource Economics, Springer Publisher, Dordrecht, pp. 2–16. (chapter 1). U.S. Department of Transport, 2008. National Motor Vehicle Crash Causation Survey: Report to Congress. DOT HS 811 059. Available from: 〈http://www-nrd.
nhtsa.dot.gov/Pubs/811059.pdf〉. Wolff H. Value of time: speeding behavior and gasoline prices, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.
2013.11.002, in press.
1 note · View note
downthetubes · 11 months ago
Text
Coming Soon: Project MK-Ultra: The Complete Edition, a mind-bending graphic novel
Out early next year from US publisher Clover Press is the mind-bending graphic collection Project MK-Ultra: The Complete Edition, by Scott Sampila, Brandon Beckner and Stewart Kenneth Moore
Out early next year from US publisher Clover Press is the mind-bending graphic collection Project MK-Ultra: The Complete Edition, by Scott Sampila, Brandon Beckner and Stewart Kenneth Moore. “Project MK-Ultra has been my labour of love over several years,” says Kenneth, who many downthetubes readers will know from his work for 2000AD and, perhaps, the recently published The Tragedie of Macbeth.…
Tumblr media
View On WordPress
1 note · View note
ivovynckier · 1 year ago
Text
youtube
Al Pacino as mayor of New York in "City Hall" (Harold Becker).
Pacino did the scene in one take.
0 notes
michigandrifter · 6 years ago
Text
True Grit 1969
Tumblr media
35 notes · View notes
meandrichard · 6 years ago
Text
Abandoning role agnosticism, or: In praise of Armitage human
Abandoning role agnosticism, or: In praise of Armitage human
Tumblr media Tumblr media
Richard Armitage as Chop in Urban and the Shed Crew — as Chop has descended into addiction.
What roles should Richard Armitage be pursuing? I have typically said: “On principle, I don’t know.”
I try to remain agnostic as to role choice, apart from believing that Armitage is at his best on stage and preferring live action of any kind to voice acting, narrations or voiceovers. But I lack data. I…
View On WordPress
20 notes · View notes
outsidetheknow · 5 years ago
Photo
Tumblr media
The Indispensable Man: How Giuliani Led Trump to the Brink of Impeachment Rudy Giuliani didn’t get the job he expected. But as unpaid personal counsel to the president and for-profit peddler of access and advice, he got the spotlight.. via NYT U.S.
0 notes